Pit Schultz on Thu, 14 Nov 96 22:55 MET |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
nettime: Markets as Work - Richard Barbrook |
MARKETS AS WORK Talk by Richard Barbrook Hypermedia Research Centre, University of Westminster (Followed by remarks of Manuel Delanda) Held at the Metaforum 3 conference, 'Under Construction' Budapest, October 13, 1996 I thought it was very interesting listening to the debate here, because I did feel a sense of deja-vu from debating with Richard Dawkins at Ars Electronica in Linz. In the sense that we're talking about the same problem. Modernity is a process which regularly changes the social, technical, political circumstances within which we live in. And therefore there is this temptation to think that new theories are the only way to explain the most recent changes - like the "paradigm shift" which Manuel Delanda has been talking about. If we look at this century, we can see that there has been a succession of new theories which have come and gone: Bolshevism, fascism, Keynesianism - and we're now witnessing the end game of post-modernism and neo-liberalism. It is interesting that - at this very moment of theoretical exhaustion - we get the importation of terms from biology, computing and physics into the social sciences. What I want to do here is to talk as a social scientist - if we can still use words like that - about the particularity of social science and to argue against the mystical positivism which we heard from Manuel Delanda. Above all, what I want to stress is that - behind his hip talk about non-linear equations and artificial life - there are some very traditional ideas derived from liberal economics. Manuel romanticises the world of small producers who freely buy and sell to each other in local markets. There are two points to make about this fantasy. First, peasant markets were not determined by supply and demand. This analysis is a completely ahistorical - as is shown in Edward Thompson's book called 'Customs in Common'. Markets in pre-modern times were set by customary prices. For manufactured goods, prices were controlled by the guilds. For agricultural goods, there was the additional sanction of the food riot. Edward Thompson makes quite clear that - when speculators did try to withdraw corn from the market to push up prices - the people would go along, open the bakeries and sell the bread at what they regarded as the customary price. Adam Smith's "free" market - as described in the 'Wealth of Nations' - was a new phenomenon in the late-eighteenth century. Sometimes the "free" market even had to be imposed on the population at the point of soldiers' bayonets! The other difficulty with romanticising small producers is that they cannot tackle the most fundamental economic problems which we face today. I don't want to defend corporate apologists like George Gilder here, but I can't understand how small peasant markets are going to organise an infrastructural works programme as large as building a fibre-optic grid. This is a big social project. We're talking in England of an expenditure of around þ20 billion. In America, it could cost around $120 billion. These problems with romanticising small producers are the reason why we need to reject Manuel's enthusiasm to throw out the old theories. We cannot ignore the ideas of "dead white males" - as they are often called in American universities. On the contrary, we need to read them, understand them and to deepen their analyses. I am a member of the Labour party. However I'm not just a leftist, but also English. England was the first urbanised bourgeois nation. We English are guilty not only of inventing liberalism, but also socialism! Therefore it is important to look at the "dead white males" who were actually present at the birth of modernity in England. Interestingly, the key thinkers of this moment weren't even English! Adam Smith was Scottish, David Ricardo was Portuguese and Karl Marx was German. But they all were fascinated by the dramatically new society which was emerging in England. Coming from its periphery, they understood how England represented a dramatic break with traditional society. If you were Adam Smith living in 18th century Edinburgh, you could visit a pre-modern - almost pre-feudal - age by going a few hundred kilometres north to the tribal Highlands. These philosophers knew personally about the great contrast between traditional and modern societies. For over two hundred years, modernity has been an on-going process of urbanisation, marketisation, statisation, democratisation, industrialisation, proletarianisation, globalisation and the rise of the spectacle. England might have been the first country to have a majority of its population living in the cities, but the same process is now going on in China when peasants pour in from the countryside to join the modern world. The Net is the intensification - the speeding up - of the process of modernity at a much higher social and technical level. Money and the state are very recent phenomena. Most people until very recently lived outside the money-commodity economy. They were subsistence peasants, sometimes even nomads. Money was for surpluses, it was what you paid your taxes with, it was what you traded for luxuries. Peasants also lived outside the state. The state came in occasionally to steal money from you, to take away your sons to fight in wars or to rampage its troops across your crops. The state was something external from the people: the tax- collector and the soldier. Modernity is the process of our inclusion within the money-commodity economy and the state. And the Net - contrary to the Californian ideologues - is intensifying this process. What are talking about here? According to the "dead white males", what was the driving force behind this process of modernity? No commodity goes to the market by itself, no machine produces by itself. Adam Smith's 'Wealth of Nations' starts with a very interesting analysis of what makes modern society superior to the tribal way of living up in the Highlands. According to Smith, this is the division and distribution of human labour. He starts with the analogy of the pin factory. Individuals making pins on their own will not do it very quickly. But, if you divide and distribute the labour of manufacturing pins between lots of individuals, suddenly productivity shoots up. Smith uses an anti-market analogy - as Braudel would call it - to explain how markets work. Because, he says, if we look at the market as a whole, the same process is going on. Some people make pins, some are peasants, others are economists and so on. By buying and selling to each other, they together create collective labour. This labour theory of value still has value today. It is not something we should see just as an explanation of how prices are determined in a marketplace. As the Russian economist Isaac Illich Rubin pointed out, the labour theory of value is also sociologically true. This is the point which Smith is making. By turning labour into a commodity, we create the basis for collective labour - we enable ourselves to work together across time and space. The thing that gave the edge to the market was that it allowed people to move between jobs, to be grouped into larger and larger conglomerations. The early political economists were fascinated by this socialisation of labour. Manuel's analytical division between markets and anti-markets can be useful in many ways, but this approach also misses this key point about the socialisation of labour. For instance, the power underpinning corporations like Microsoft or Netscape is their ability to employ thousands of workers. These organisations coordinate collective labour across time and space. The Net is deepening this process by enabling more people to work within a global marketplace and to create global organisations. Let me tell you a story about a friend of ours called Eva. She runs a cybercafe in London called Cyberia which has franchises in places like Dublin, New York, Paris, Rotterdam, Tokyo and Bangkok. How can she coordinate a small business across three continents? IRC-channels turned out to be a very good way that managers from the different cybercafes could get together to talk about their common problems! This is a good example how economies of scale are now being generated on a wider scale through the Net. This is why we must understand that we're still living within the process of modernity. This is why we cannot abandon the fundamental analyses of modernity first made in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. We still have to study political economy. We live within a statised, money-commodity society. These phenomena have not gone away. This is why I find it bizarre that Manuel quotes the work of Fernand Braudel against any analysis derived from political economy. Braudel was a member of the Annales School in France. Far from being anti-Marxists, these historians were socialists! Braudel himself says in the book quoted by Manuel that he supports "socialism from above and spontaneity from below." Similarly Harry Braverman was closely associated with 'Monthly Review', which is an American academic journal run by self-styled Marxists. Why do Braudel and Braverman need to use theories from the nineteenth century? Because the work of political economists provides you with useful tools for comprehending empirical reality. The methodology of sociology is not the same as the methodology of physics or biology. What I want to stress is that social events are non-repeatable. It's not just that there is friction and mess in empirical reality. More importantly, history is a process of continual non-repeatable changes, especially since the advent of modernity. The founders of political economy witnessed the decline of traditional societies based on family relations, patriarchy and religious belief. They understood that the new world of states and markets was a place of things - a place where people relate to each other indirectly through things rather directly through personal relationships. Above all, by allowing our society to be organised through things, we've have unleashed the dynamic process of the continual socialisation of labour. It is because of this crucial insight that I think it is important for us to look again at the writings of those "dead white males" and the people who have build upon their work. We need to understand how really existing capitalism evolves as a process if we want to know what we can do within this form of society whether we work for wages, are company owners or even doing things for free. In particular, I'm influenced by the work of a group of French economists who emerged out of the radical protests of the '60s. Michel Aglietta, Alain Lipietz, Robert Boyer and Benjamin Coriat are the leading members of what is called the Regulation School. Lipietz is associated with the Greens, but most of these economists are either in the French Socialist Party or closely associated with it. Like Braudel, they believe that the state has an important role to play within the economy, but they're also interested in encouraging the spontaneity of the market and community involvement. As Social Democrats, they are advocates of the mixed economy. It is interesting to compare their analysis with the one put forward by Manuel. For the Regulation School, Venice could not be the founder of modern capitalism because its wealth was based on trade between two self-sufficient agricultural entities: the Ottoman and Holy Roman Empires. Instead they locate the birth of capitalism in England. This was the first society where all basic necessities had to be obtained through people buying and selling goods and services to each other. They then trace the process of modernity through nineteenth century liberalism to the successful development in the post-war era of Fordism: our contemporary society of mass production and mass consumption. At the centre of their analysis is why Fordism in Western Europe, America and Japan has since entered into a long period of crisis. Unlike neo-liberals, they're not just interested in the size of companies, the regulatory role of the state and the globalisation of markets. Like Adam Smith, the Regulation School believe that the continual socialisation of labour is the key to understanding the process of modernity - including the crisis of Fordism. >From the late-'60s onwards, the rigid hierarchies of the Fordist factory system became an obstacle to raising the productivity of labour. By concentrating the workforce within such large organisations, it became very difficult to innovate at great speed. Above all, the factory system created the conditions for a long period of labour unrest across the industrialised world. In response, neo-liberal policies of deregulation and marketisation were adopted as a way of redisciplining workers and breaking up the rigidities of the factory system. The Net is a good