Keith Hart on Fri, 9 Feb 2007 11:48:40 +0100 (CET) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
<nettime> money is always personal and impersonal |
Apologies for inflicting yet another rumination on this topic to the list. I just wonder if I am making progress with my idee fixe. Keith Money is always personal and impersonal /Money, society, religion/ Money is often portrayed as a lifeless object separated from persons, whereas in fact it is a creation of human beings, imbued with the collective spirit of the living and the dead. Money, as a token of society, must be impersonal in order to connect each individual to the universe of relations to which they belong. The economists capture this aspect of money in their abstract models of universal exchange. But people make everything personal, especially their relations with the conditions of their collective existence. Anthropologists and sociologists are sensitive to the meaning of money in the context of people?s everyday lives. The unity of this two-sided relationship is universal, but its incidence is highly variable, providing a thread for the study of human history as a whole and in all its diversity. The ways we combine the personal and impersonal aspects of money have much in common with religion. Religion /binds/ each of us to an external force, lending stability to our meaningful interaction with the world and providing an anchor for our volatility. What we know intimately are our own everyday lives, the mundane features of our personal routines; but these lives are subject to larger forces whose origins we do not know ? natural disasters, social revolutions and death. We recognize these unknown causes of our fate to be at once individual and collective; and religion is the organized attempt to bridge the gap between the known and the unknown, between the world of ordinary experience and an extraordinary world that lies beyond it. Emile Durkheim held that what is ultimately unknown to us is our collective being in society. The chaos of everyday life thus attains a measure of order to the extent that it is informed by ideas representing the social facts of a shared existence. Humanity?s task today is to assume responsibility for life as a whole on this planet and religion is indispensable to that end. Given the obscene inequality and destructiveness of a world society whose driving force is capitalism, it is not surprising that many consider the system of money today to be the opposite of religious or at least to constitute a false religion whose priests are the economists. Indeed religion itself has a fairly murderous reputation. But markets and money are essential, indeed universal means of connecting the everyday life of each individual to the widest horizons of our collective existence. They form a field of social experience where the personal and the impersonal, the inside and the outside, the known and the unknown inevitably are joined, requiring us to devise effective ways of bringing them together as a meaningful whole. This may ? probably should ? entail making a break with the organization of money as we know it. But it will do us no good to repudiate money or markets as such, since they are central to human civilization, past, present and future. I attribute this position to Marcel Mauss, Durkheim?s nephew and collaborator. It is well-known that Mauss considered /The Gift/ to embody personal, social and spiritual ties in economic life; but he also aimed to show how impersonal money and markets already contain these qualities and might, with appropriate social engineering, develop them more fully. /Mauss on money and markets/ Malinowski says in the /Economic Journal/ (1923), ?/Currency/ as a rule means a medium of exchange and standard of value, and none of the Massim valuables fulfill these functions?. But Mauss replies, On this reasoning...there has only been money when precious things...have been really made into currency ? namely have been inscribed and impersonalized, and detached from any relationship with any legal entity, whether collective or individual, other than the state that mints them... One only defines in this way a second type of money -- our own. He argues rather that valuables used in archaic exchange are like money in that they ?...have purchasing power, and this power has a figure set on it.?. He also takes Malinowski to task for reproducing in his typology of transactions the ideological opposition between commercial self-interest and the free gift. Durkheim, in seeking to refute the utilitarian individualism of English economics, claimed that this approach obscured the social glue of ?the non-contractual element in the contract? which made the economy possible ? a combination of law, state, customs, morality and shared history that it was the sociologist?s task to make more visible. Mauss later had to take a position on the Bolshevik revolution and its aftermath. He was highly critical of the Bolsheviks? coercive resort to violence, especially against the most active classes, and of their destruction of the market economy along with confidence and good will. He advocated an ?economic movement from below?, in the form of syndicalism, co-operation and mutual insurance. His greatest hopes were for a consumer democracy driven by the co-operative movement. He even enjoyed a brief period as a financial commentator on the exchange rate crisis of 1922 and argued that ?economic revolutions are always monetary?. This economic movement from below was for him a secular version of what can be found in the religions of archaic societies, as well as in the central phenomena of exchange described in /The Gift/. They are all ?total social facts?, in the sense that they bring into play the whole of society and all its institutions ? legal, economic, religious and aesthetic. Against the contemporary move to replace markets with authoritarian states, Mauss insisted that the complex interplay between individual freedom and social obligation is synonymous with the human condition and that markets and money are universal, if not in their current impersonal form, because they give vent to this interplay. He concluded that the attempt to create a free market for private contracts is utopian and just as unrealizable as its antithesis, a collective based solely on altruism. Human institutions everywhere are founded on the unity of individual and society, freedom and obligation, self-interest and concern for others. Modern capitalism rests on an unsustainable attachment to one of these poles and it will take a social revolution to restore a humane balance. Perhaps the chief message of /The Gift/ concerns method. We must follow the example of the historians and observe what is given, rather than split up social phenomena into separate abstractions. The reality is always a concrete person acting in society ? ?the middle-class Frenchman, the Melanesian of this or that island?. Then sociologists and anthropologists will furnish psychologists with material they can use, while maintaining their distinctive pursuit of the social whole and of group behavior as a whole. This is Marcel Mauss?s manifesto for how he will carry forward his uncle?s academic legacy. /Impersonal money and its critics/ So where did impersonal money and markets come from and how impersonal are they? Money was traditionally impersonal so that it could retain its value when it moved between people who might not even know each other. If you drop a coin or banknote on the floor, whoever picks it up can spend it just as easily as you can. Money in this form is an instrument detached from the person who uses it. The expansion of trade often depended on this objectivity of the medium of exchange and economists have long debated whether money?s value derives from its being a scarce commodity or from the guarantees made by states who issued it. Bank credit on the other hand has always been more directly personal, being linked to the trustworthiness of individuals and, in the case of paper instruments such as cheques, issued by them. The idea that transactions involving money are essentially amoral comes from its impersonal form, but until recently, in most societies, the bulk of economic life was carried out by people who knew each other and were able to discriminate between individuals on the basis of experience. Keynes held that modern money was as old as the invention of cities and, with them, the state, that is to say, as old as agrarian civilization. Bank money is almost as ancient, but it took on renewed significance for western economic history in the Renaissance. Modern national currencies are the result of a merger of state and banking systems, leading some authors, especially French, to stress the importance of sovereignty in the making of impersonal money. This strand of thinking is very much in a minority today, when the market model of an eighteenth century revolution in political economy holds undisputed sway, especially in the English-speaking world. In liberal ideology, money is a commodity just like any other; its payment in exchange releases buyer and seller from the need for any ongoing relationship, allowing both the money and what it buys to be separated from their owners as private property. The parties to the exchange are conceived of as individuals devoid of social or cultural ties. The origin of such markets is said to lie in the ?natural economy? of primitive barter, where the only thing missing is the money, which appears later to make good the inefficiencies of the older system. The impersonality of money and of the transactions it facilitates is here derived not from a universal sovereign, but from the anonymity of homogeneous individuals meeting in the marketplace, with price resolving their superficial differences. The value of commodities is traced to a common origin in human labour. This is less a description or analysis of money and markets than an ideological programme for displacing states from their central position in the economy, a programme that was later reversed in the alliance between states and corporations that spawned what I call ?national capitalism?. Mainstream economics has always had its critics, led by Karl Polanyi who, in /The Great Transformation/, developed a line of attack on liberal capitalism and the economists that proved to be remarkably durable. For him, impersonal markets and money have only recently displaced more humane institutional arrangements from the social organization of economy. These were society?s way of ensuring material provisioning for its members and they subjected exchange to moral, i.e. personal considerations. The self-regulating market dehumanized exchange. This would be bad enough if it were limited to what people make, like hats and shoes; but the market principle was extended to the conditions of our collective existence and these are not consciously made by human beings ? Nature, Society (in the form of Money) and Humanity, reduced to the ?fictitious commodities? of land, capital and labour. Impersonal markets thus threatened human survival itself and inevitably provoked a social reaction in the form of people?s numerous attempts to restore a measure of personal and collective control over their lives. Polanyi drew on the examples of ancient Greece and pre-colonial West Africa to show the historical limits of /homo economicus/. In both cases, marketplaces were peripheral and relations within them were social and personal. Money was largely restricted to ?special-purpose? forms, with ?general-purpose money? being associated with the European powers. His approach has subsequently come to be identified with the claim that the economy in non-industrial societies is ?embedded? in social institutions and that ?the great transformation? of the nineteenth century consisted in the self-regulating market becoming ?disembedded? from society. The idea of ?embeddedness? has become the calling sign of all those, especially economic sociologists, who reject the impersonal model of money and markets offered by mainstream economics. Chief of these is Viviana Zelizer, whose /The Social Meaning of Money/ takes the fight to the core of contemporary capitalism, the United States, at a time when the dollar?s national monopoly was being forged, the decades following the Civil War. Zelizer shows that the achievement of centralized control over money had to overcome a plethora of institutional alternatives and sustained political resistance. Moreover, even when the idea of a single currency had been more or less accepted, American commerce still spawned parallel currencies in the form of trading tokens and the like, as a way of dividing the market through particularistic ties. Her main finding is that people in general refused to treat the impersonal money in their possession as an undifferentiated thing, choosing rather to ?earmark? it for their own purposes, keeping some separate for paying the food bills, some as savings for a holiday and so on. Her focus is mainly on areas that remain invisible to economists? gaze: domestic transactions, gifts, charities. There can be little dispute that people everywhere personalize money, bending it to their own purposes and devising numerous social instruments to do so. To the extent that the functioning of money and markets is understood exclusively in terms of impersonal models, the neglect of this dimension is surely significant. But critics sometimes claim that the economists? impersonal approach is irrelevant or even harmful to human interests. The economy exists at a number of levels and not just those of the person, the family or local groups. The more inclusive levels are made possible to a substantial degree by the relative impersonality of money and markets. It will not do to replace one pole of a dialectical pair with the other. We are today more than ever aware of our economic interdependence in a world of markets and money that has been unified by a digital revolution in communications. We need to understand this emerging universe of virtual abstraction in order to make meaningful connection with it from the perspective of our everyday lives. /Money in the digital revolution/ The world economy is being transformed once more by radical reductions in the cost of producing a basic commodity, in this case the transfer of information. There was a time when commodities traded internationally were things extracted from the ground and services were performed locally in person. Now the person answering your business call could be located anywhere in the world and a growing number of service jobs are exposed to global competition. Vast profits are to be made in entertainment, education, the media, finance, software and all the other information services. But the digital revolution poses specific problems for accumulation. The saying goes that ?information wants to be free? and certainly there is continuous downward pressure on prices in this sector arising from the ease of copying proprietary products. And there is another aspect of this revolution that bears directly on the relationship between the personal and impersonal dimensions of social life. The cheapening of the cost of information transfers has considerable consequence for the character of long-distance market relations. The era of mass production and consumption may be ending as a result. It is now possible to attach to transactions at distance a lot of information about individuals. For example, amazon.com keeps a record of every book bought from them and they make recommendations for new purchases on this basis. This is similar to the small bookseller who reserves a book for a favorite customer, but now it all takes place anonymously at distance. Some firms are already moving towards a system known as Customer Relations Maintenance (CRM) based on data banks that know no limit in scope. This enables them to target buyers who generate above average revenues, to remind them of the need to buy something for their wife?s birthday and so on. Nowhere has this process gone further than in the market for personal credit. A generation ago personal purchasing power could only be extended by approaching ones bank manager for an overdraft. Now the number and variety of financial instruments on offer is growing exponentially and these are often customized to individual needs. It is not quite the same as ordering a suit from Savile Row in the nineteenth century, but the trend is definitely to restore personal identity to what were until not long ago largely impersonal contracts. Of course, powerful organizations have access to huge processors with which to manipulate an often unknowing public; and rich individuals have always experienced markets and money as personalities in their own right. But for many people these developments have introduced new conditions of engagement with the impersonal economy. The line between personal and impersonal society is shifting, with significant implications for individual and collective agency. Twentieth century society was based on impersonal economic institutions that made most people feel largely powerless. The idea is now slowly taking root that society is less an oppressive structure out there and more a subjective capacity that allows each of us to learn how to manage our relations with others. Money is a good symbol of this shift. It first took the form of objects outside ourselves (coins) of which we usually had a greater need than the available supply; but of late it has increasingly been manifested as personal credit, in the form of digitalized transfers mediated by plastic cards and telephone wires, thereby altering the notions of economic agency that we bring to participation in markets. If modern society has always been supposed to be individualistic, only now perhaps is the individual emerging as a social force to be reckoned with. This claim rests on a single overwhelming fact, that large amounts of information can now be processed cheaply, making possible the repersonalization of complex economic life. In the process the assumptions that supported mass society for a century are being undermined. To speak of ?repersonalization? is probably misleading, since society and the individual, the impersonal and the personal, are equally necessary to human existence; and working out specific ways of combining them is problematic. We have to take society as it comes, but we can also try to make it. If repersonalization means the declining effectiveness of the bureaucratic powers with which we are familiar, it also opens the way perhaps to a new feudalism. That is why we should not think of the present as a shift from the impersonal to the personal, but rather as a change affecting the construction of the relationship between the two. If economy has become more impersonal, responding in part to the increased scale and complexity of exchange, this does not mean that the personal basis of economic relations has been displaced, nor indeed that the dialectic of individual and collective agency was ever absent from societies where modern money and markets were marginal. Economic history is dialectical. Most people are quite anxious about being economically dependent on impersonal and anonymous institutions. This is an immense force for reversing the historical pattern of alienation on which the modern economy has been built. So any renewed emphasis on human personality and concrete social relations in economic life depends on the search for forms of impersonal society appropriate to such a goal. /Conclusion: what is money?/ What then is money? All the textbooks give the same definitions: it is a means of payment; a unit of account; a standard of value; a store of wealth. These conventions do not capture the most important feature of money, its evolution as a means of human interaction in society. Money is /made/ by us, but for most people it has long been something scarce which we /take/ passively whenever possible, without any sense of its being our collective creation. From having been an object produced by remote authorities, it is becoming more obviously a subjective expression of our own will; and this development is mirrored in the shift from ?real? to ?virtual? money. In the last 300 years or so, the money form has evolved from metallic coins and ledger entries through paper notes to electronic digits. In the process, money is becoming dematerialized, losing any shred of a claim that it is founded on the natural scarcity of precious metals. Even the authority of states, who stamped coinage and issued the notes with which we are still most familiar as money, cannot long survive the electronic blizzard that is money in the age of the internet. Money is a universal measure of value, but its specific form is not yet as universal as the method humanity has devised to measure time all round the world. It is purchasing power, a means of buying and selling in markets. It counts wealth and status. It is a store of memory linking individuals to their various communities, a kind of memory bank and thus a source of identity. As a symbolic medium, it conveys information through a system of signs that relies more on numbers than words. A lot more circulates with money than the goods and services it buys. Money?s significance lies in the synthesis it promotes of impersonal abstraction and personal meaning, objectification and subjectivity, analytical reason and synthetic narrative. Its social power comes from the fluency of its mediation between infinite potential and finite determination. In /The Memory Bank/, I sketched a possible scenario of financial history that leads from state-made money to greater reliance on personal credit. This does entail, to a degree, a repersonalization of economic life, as exchange absorbs more and more information about persons. Plastic credit cards are just the first step in this process. But if this could be represented as a step towards greater humanism in economy, we need to recognize also that it entails increased dependence on the impersonal organization of governments and corporations, on impersonal abstraction of the sort associated with the computing operations and on the need for impersonal standards and social guarantees for contractual exchange of wide scope. If persons are to make a comeback in the post-modern economy, it will not be on a face-to-face basis, but as bits on a screen who sometimes materialize as living people in the present. In the process we may become less weighed down by the concept of money as an objective force, more open to the idea that it is simply a way of keeping track of complex social networks that we each generate as active individual subjects. This should give reason for optimism that money could once again take a wide variety of forms compatible with both personal agency and human interdependence at every level from the local to the global. But we should not imagine that such a process is likely to be achieved soon or easily. Marcel Mauss was far-sighted when he sought to trace the foundations of the modern economy to its origin in the archaic gift, rather than in primitive barter as the liberal myth holds. The idea of money as personal credit, linked less to the history of state coinage than to the acknowledgement of private debts, is consistent both with Mauss?s emphasis and with my argument here. If the meaning of money lies in the myriad acts of remembering that link individuals to their communities, money in its many forms helps us keep track of connections with others as the principal instrument of collective memory. We can now enter circuits of exchange based on voluntary association and defined by special currencies of the sort pioneered in LETS schemes. At the other extreme, we will participate as individuals in global markets of infinite scope, using international moneys-of-account, such as the dollar and euro, electronic payment systems of various sorts or even direct barter via the internet. In many ways, it will be a world whose plurality of association, even fragmentation, will resemble feudalism more than the Roman empire. This is an unsettling prospect; for who would want to be prey to personal rule by gangsters unrestrained by impersonal law? That is why we urgently need to harness the potential of current economic trends to develop more effective impersonal institutions (?the state?) at the level of world society as well as below. In money?s potential to sustain universal connection lies one indispensable means to that end; but this will not be realized if it retains its modern form.** In our rapidly urbanizing world, people will expect to use any economic freedom they win for themselves to calculate the costs and benefits of the many contracts they enter in the course of normal daily life. By emphasizing the means of extending social credit to responsible persons, we may be able to address more effectively the causes and remedies of what makes contemporary society so unequal. The sociologists, anthropologists and alternative economists will not get far by harping on about how people already impose personal and social controls over money and exchange. That is the everyday world as most of us know it. We need ways of reaching the parts we don?t know and of averting the ruin they could bring down on us all. Searching for the significance of money or for its wider social meaning is like asking why anyone would believe in God. Of course we made Him up, just as we made and make Money up. We believe because we have to ? and faith is the glue sticking past and future together in the present. Since our ephemeral economic transactions depend on using money, it seems to be more stable than the relations it expresses. Whether we like it or not, money is the ocean we swim in these days. Despite or because of this, its role in human affairs continues to be demonized and the attempt to return it to the marginal role it was confined to in agrarian civilizations always finds a ready audience. Money surely generates value and significance in human interactions as much as it erodes them. It is a symbol of each person?s relationship to society. This may be conceived of as a durable ground on which to stand, anchoring identity in a collective memory whose concrete symbol is money; or as the outcome of a more creative process in which we each generate the personal credit linking us to society. The second view requires us to abandon the notion that society rests on abstract grounds more solid than the transient exchanges we participate in. Few people at present are prepared to take that step. When the meaning of money is seen to be what each of us makes of it, we may be less inclined to think of Money as the somewhat archaic God of capitalism that it has become. # distributed via <nettime>: no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a moderated mailing list for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: majordomo@bbs.thing.net and "info nettime-l" in the msg body # archive: http://www.nettime.org contact: nettime@bbs.thing.net