McKenzie Wark on Sun, 10 Feb 2002 18:28:02 +0100 (CET) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
[Nettime-bold] Culture, Economy, Information |
The Property Question: Culture, Economy, Information McKenzie Wark <mw35@nyu.edu> [for Tiziana] I believe that Marxist-inspired media studies and cultural studies lost its way in part because it has not kept up with the changes in the property form. The position I want to advocate is a critique of the kinds of postmarxism that are foundational for many kinds of cultural studies, but one that does not retreat back to the economic determinism that postmarxist theories were meant to overcome. I've called this paper 'The Property Question' after a line from The Communist Manifesto, where Marx and Engels write of the role of the communist minorities within the democratic movements of the time: "in all these movements they bring to the front, as the leading question in each, the property question, no matter what its degree of development at the time." Marx also nominates an answer to the property question, for communist militants: "centralise all instruments of production in the hands of the state."1 As we know, this solution did not work out so well. Putting all property in the hands of the state merely created a ruling class who ruled directly through the state. The revolutions of 1989 have to my mind decisively settled the fate of Marx's answer to the property question. All the same, I think Marx asked the right question, even if he didn't offer the right answer. The leading question for those concerned with justice and equality is still the property question. When I was a radical undergraduate, everyone was reading the works of Louis Althusser and Antonio Gramsci. In their very different ways, these two writers had addressed certain inadequacies in the Marxist conception of the social totality. There was a strong desire at that time to extract from Marx a comprehensive social theory. Various tactical writings and incomplete empirical investigations by Marx were picked over for the elements of a totalising theory of what the Althusserians called the 'social formation'. A problem that emerged, on the basis of a few slender quotes from Marx, was the problem of 'base and superstructure'. Economic matters appeared to be the engine of social change in Marxist historiography. Political and cultural matters were merely superstructural. Althusser and Gramsci broke with this kind of economic determinism. In Gramsci's writings, there's a struggle on the political and cultural level in which classes try to form a ruling block through which to cement their power by extracting the consent of the subordinated classes. For Gramsci, oppositional politics was a matter of a 'war of position', in which the working class could seek influence in political and cultural institutions in the struggle for 'hegemony'. Althusser and his circle set themselves the task of a close reading of Marx, and came up with an interpretation of his historiography that claimed a 'relative autonomy' for the political and cultural levels of the social formation. The economic was held to be determinate 'in the last instance' -- a moment which 'never arrives'. Althusser was heavily influenced by Maoist thought, which viewed revolution as "putting politics in command", rather than one that awaits the maturation of the economic 'base'. For many scholars working in the humanities who were looking for a radical social theory, both these currents seemed promising. They had the advantage of a more complex and sometimes more subtle social theory than economic reductionism. They also offered a more positive account of the potential for social change than the Frankfurt school marxists. The Frankfurt school developed a social theory which also saw the economic as a determinate instance, but in a much more subtle and pervasive manner. The alienation and reification of all social relations proceeds from their development as homologies of the commodity relation. Whether one turned to Adorno and Horkheimer, to Lukacs or even Guy Debord, this seemed a somewhat pessimistic basis for thinking about culture under capitalism. So attention shifted to Althusser and Gramsci. A number of influential currents brought the insights of these two thinkers together. The writers associated with the journal Screen, Ernesto Laclau and Chantal Mouffe, and the group around Stuart Hall at the Centre for Contemporary Cultural Studies, also known as the Birmingham school. (Or in Australia, the work of Bob Connell.) I don't want to go into the details of the positions of these authors, or their ongoing dispute with economic determinist scholars, such as Graham Murdock and Nicholas Garnham. At the end of the day I think both groups were reading Marx the wrong way. My critique does not depend on some claim to Marxological orthodoxy. I don't think the answer lies in fidelity to the master-text. But there are productive intellectual tools in Marx that have been to some extent ignored. One should pause, however, to note that there was a certain convenience in formulas such as Althusser's, which asserted the 'relative autonomy' of the political and ideological (or cultural) 'instances'. It meant that scholarship could function within its conventional disciplinary boundaries and still claim allegiance to the radical project. The problem was that in this capitulation to specialised knowledge, a more holistic grasp of the dynamics of the commodity economy was lost. The opportunity for a critique of knowledge as a form of intellectual property, was, incidentally, also lost. Meanwhile, the economic reductionist approaches continued on their merry way, and often produced detailed studies of the development of the commodification of information, knowledge, culture and communication. This is particularly true in the field of critical communication studies in the United States, around the work of Herbert Schiller. However, my claim is that this school did not develop a theoretical understanding of the changes in the form of commodity relations to go with the often telling descriptions of its progress. The same goes for the Italian autonomist Marxists, who did much to extend an analysis of class self-formation into the realms of the information economy, but at the end of the day were still using concepts premised on the prior analysis of industrial capital. To speak of material and immaterial labour, or the social factory, is to extend metaphors to the breaking point rather than to begin the analysis again, at the critical point, at which information becomes something that can indeed be subjected to the regime of exchange. What was missing, in all of these approaches, was a close attention to the 'property question'. Marx's insight was that the legal and social form of private property gave rise to a class relation. On the one side, there were those who use the legal apparatus to secure property as private property, and on the other hand there were those who found themselves dispossessed as a result. The privatisation of the property relation creates classes in the modern sense. Private property is an abstract relation, indifferent to the characteristics of whoever is in possession of it. It gives rise to abstract classes, thrown together in spite of their cultures and traditions. Now, it is important to remember that Marx traces this development of the privatisation of property through two distinct phases. One is the privatisation of land, the other is the privatisation of productive resources in the form of capital. While they overlap historically, these are analytically two distinct moments. Different innovations in property form are involved. Different kinds of ruling class arise. Different kinds of economic return accrue to these distinct forms of ownership. Marx takes over from Ricardo an understanding of the difference between profit and rent, the returns to capital and land respectively. My argument regarding the property question is this: there are already two moments in the privatisation of property in Marx's analysis. Why not a third? I consider intellectual property to be a third, distinct form of private property, which gives rise to a third, distinct class antagonism. Historically it proceeds alongside the privatisation of land and capital. Intellectual property emerges -- and not without a struggle -- in the 18th century. But it is analytically distinct. Information is a different kind of property. It produces, and is produced by, quite new and different kinds of class relation. A key tenet of the Marxist approach is that property is not an artifact of nature. We did not come down from the trees in prehistoric times equipped with stock portfolios. That nature is not a free market economy is evident in the fact that nature gets along fine without corporate lawyers, management consultants and advertising account executives. Private property, as a social creation, is something that becomes progressively more abstract. Capital represents an advance over privately held land. Intellectual property further abstracts the concept of property. Private property comes first to land, which becomes a universal and interchangeable substance. It is extended to all other physical, productive assets, and finally to information itself, to something that can even exist independently of any particular material support. In three distinct phases, the particular becomes abstract. By following the property question through from its transformation of peasant economies into commodity economies, on through the development of commodity production in manufactures, and on to it current phase of the commodification of all aspects of information, one can construct a quite distinctive view of the relationship that emerges between culture and economy. Consider, for a moment, some of the things we have before us requiring some explanation. The transformation of national conglomerates into multinational media companies. The rise of media empires based around the leadership of a powerful individual. The convergence of media businesses in different industries. The transformation of leading manufacturers into global industrial subcontractors. The rise of the brand and the trademark as a key asset in corporate portfolios the rise of patents as a key asset in corporate value and power. And consider some of the legal and regulatory changes that accompany these developments The progressive strengthening of intellectual property rights within the developed world. The rise of intellectual property as a significant issue in international trade agreements Vigorous prosecution of copyright and trademark infringements Deregulation of telephony, cable, broadcasting and other media industries. Some of these phenomena are already becoming the subject of a popular radical literature. Books like Naomi Klein's No Logo, and Thomas Carr Frank's One Market Under God address some of these topics with original reporting and vigorous prose. But it seems to me that a comprehensive account of the current stage of commodity production is yet lacking. One might mention also the critique of the streets. Why is it that people in Karachi or Genoa want to trash McDonalds? Is it because they found their fries to soggy? Or is it out of an intuition that McDonalds is a sign of something? That something might be in part globalisation or Americanisation, but it might in part be a recognition of the role the trademark has come to play in a new economy of the sign, a new regime of commodity production. I say commodity production rather than 'capitalism' because I think that this is no longer capitalism, but something else. But let's take a more comprehensive look at this. Let's take a look first at the underdeveloped world. The privatisation of land is still an ongoing struggle there. In many places, capitalism hasn't really happened. The ruling class is in some measure a land owning class. The land seizures in Zimbabwe, the Zapatista movement in Chiapas, Mexico, the liberation movements active in Irian Jaya and other parts of the Indonesia archipeligo might be examples. But the other story in the developing world is the extent to which it is becoming the home of old fashioned capitalism. It's not just the unskilled jobs that have fled from the United States, Europe and Japan, but increasingly the skilled jobs as well. The surplus populations thrown off the land by its privitisation in Thailand or Mexico find themselves transformed into the new globalised working class. Now let's take a look at the developed world -- or what Paul Gilroy calls the overdeveloped world. Capitalism is moving from the centre to the periphery. Companies in the developed world are divesting themselves of their productive. Their power no longer rests on that. It rests on the management and development of trademarks and patents. Whether one makes drugs, cars, shoes, recorded music or computers, it is not land, not capital, but intellectual property that is at the core of one's business. What replaces capitalism in the developed world? In A Hacker Manifesto, I talk about the rise of vectoralist society, and of a vectoralist ruling class.2 It is perhaps not the most gainly coinage, but for the moment, it is the best I can do. 'Vector' is a word common to geometry, physics, epidemology. In the latter, it means the potential carrier for a disease. Bodily fluids are a vector for HIV. Water is a vector for cholera. We've heard a lot lately about the spores that are the vector for Anthrax. I apply this term to information to mean the potential mode of transmission across space and time. It is not enough to own the private property rights to information. The key is the ownership and control of the vector of transmission, through space or time. Hence the leading fraction of the vectoralist class are the owners of the vectors. The Vanderbilts and Carnegies made their fortunes identifying strategic points in the production cycle of capital and seizing control of them -- steel production, or railways. The Vanderbilts and Carnegies of our time are Ted Turner, Rupert Murdoch, who saw the value of owning stocks or flows of information -- news and movies -- but also the strategic value of owning the vector, be it satellite, cable or the old fashioned printed page. The vectoralist class, as owners of the vector, confront a producer class. Just as the landlords confronted peasants, and capitalists confronted workers, the vectoralist confronts the hacker class. All creators of intellectual property might be included in this class, whether copyrights or patents. This isn't the first theory of class to try to come up with some way of thinking about 'symbolic analysts' as Robert Reich called them. There are plenty of theories of the new middle class, the intelligentsia and so on. But none to my knowledge conceive of this other class as constitute on the same basis as all the others -- out of the private property form. They usually require the addition of some heterogeneous principle into class analysis. The reason for this is perhaps the only very gradual emergence of intellectual property as a property form of significance and currency. The other reason is surely the bias of existing theories towards conceiving of the economic as in some sense a more material realm. This is true of both economic determinist theories and the culturalist theories that reacted against them. Neither think of information as something that can be directly articulated to property and economy. Now lets take a look at the phenomena this analysis can help explain: The prominence of intellectual property issues in the WTO, ranging from the concessions on 'patent medicines' for the developing world to stricter anti-piracy protection. The restructuring of major corporations around intellectual property and the remarkable rise in 'outsourcing' of manufacturing. The new ruling class is no longer prepared to compromise with nations and peoples, and pursues the opportunity to organise all their activities vectorally, on a global scale. The rise of media conglomerates, with few tangible assets on their books besides their intellectual property portfolio, and the means to realise its value -- a vectoral arsenal for putting intellectual property in circulation. The campaign against 'leakage' from the new intellectual property economy -- whether its generic drugs or Napster file downloads. Push to redesign network architecture around proprietary platforms, rather than the open platform of the internet. One could go on, but it seems to me that in a time of volatility in the economic and technological order, it seems appropriate to look for theory that addresses this agenda. The people make meaning, but not with the media of their own choosing. The degree to which media -- or in indeed all aspects of intellectual property -- are subject to democratic control is a way of thinking about what otherwise disparate struggles may have in common. Media and cultural studies has acquired a readerly cast from its history as an offshoot of the study of literature. Our Leavisite ancestors speak to us of the democratic potential of equipping students with the power to read. Raymond Williams gave this impulse an explicitly Marxist twist. But in the process, attention drifted toward the superstructures, away from an economic 'base' that was too narrowly conceived. But what was lost in the process was the property question. I would suggest that the property question lies at the nexus between reading and writing, between consumption and production. If, like Toni Negri we look toward the free potential of the productive abilities of the people, then I think we have to look where Negri neglects to look -- the property question. Particularly if our task is to articulate theory that works at the nexus of teaching students not only how to consume texts but how to produce them. The possibilities for free production, as opposed to production entirely circumscribed by the logic of the commodity hinge on the future direction of intellectual property. If one were to look for the practice that might provide the impetus for such a theory, one need look no further than the 'collaborative filtering' of listservers such as nettime. They provide a working instance of a practical challenge to the property question. A reinvigoration of the practice of a critical theory, against the institutionalised weight of the academy's hypocritical theory. Notes: 1. Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, 'Manifesto of the Communist Party', in David Fernbach (ed), The Revolutions of 1848: Political Writings, Volume 1, Penguin, Harmondsworth, 1978, p98, p86 2. McKenzie Wark, 'A Hacker Manifesto', http://www.feelergauge.net/ ___________________________________________________ http://www.feelergauge.net/projects/hackermanifesto/version_2.0/ ... we no longer have roots, we have aerials ... ___________________________________________________ _________________________________________________________________ Join the worlds largest e-mail service with MSN Hotmail. http://www.hotmail.com _______________________________________________ Nettime-bold mailing list Nettime-bold@nettime.org http://amsterdam.nettime.org/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/nettime-bold