R. A. Hettinga on 14 Mar 2001 12:53:09 -0000 |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
[Nettime-bold] network effects |
--- begin forwarded text Date: Wed, 14 Mar 2001 01:18:57 -0600 Reply-To: Law & Policy of Computer Communications <CYBERIA-L@LISTSERV.AOL.COM> Sender: Law & Policy of Computer Communications <CYBERIA-L@LISTSERV.AOL.COM> From: Stan Liebowitz <liebowit@UTDALLAS.EDU> Subject: network effects To: CYBERIA-L@LISTSERV.AOL.COM I apologize for the length of this posting, but I am trying to cover a lot of territory. I have seen some, but not all, of the messages that occurred a few weeks ago having to do with network effects. The ideas are not that complicated but one does need to take some time in understanding them and also learning what the terms mean. My webpage http://wwwpub.utdallas.edu/~liebowit/netpage.html has links to most of the articles I have written (with Margolis) on the subject. As far as qualifications, Margolis and I are considered at least among the leading authorities on the subject. That, of course doesn't make what we say correct. But we can not be dismissed as cranks or crackpots. Besides the journal articles (which were edited at Yale, Chicago, U of Washington, Berkeley and Harvard) we have written the entry for 'network externality' in Palgrave's dictionary of Law and Economics (Macmillan), the Encyclopedia of Law and Economics (Edward Elgar), and the forthcoming Handbook of Telecommunication Economics (Elsevier). Each of these entries is between 5000 and 10000 words, and each was solicited by these well-respected publications. For those of you who can't abide the idea that the Independent Institute might publish good work, a collection of our papers on these subjects (edited by Peter Lewin) is being published this year by NYU/Macmillan press. Prior to my current position at UT Dallas, I had been on the faculty at Rochester and Chicago, and except for a now completed three year stint as associate dean of academics (i.e. research), have always been in research. Margolis has always been in research, except for his current stint (third year) as the chairman of his economics department. I shouldn't have to tell you this but the level of discourse has descended to such a low level that questions about these facts arose. There has been so much misinformation written, and such hostility that I thought I would make a few points to start: 1. Network effects are real and often important. Fax machines and telephones are two markets where network effects are clearly central. (These, by the way, are known as direct network effects). So Margolis and I never claimed that network effects didn't exist or weren't important. 2. The theories that we were critical of claimed the network effects locked-in products and standards that were clearly inferior to alternatives. Most importantly, even when the costs of switching was low enough that it made sense to switch, these theories claimed that coordination failures among consumers would keep the switch from being made. [e.g., we all prefer beta, but none of us think anyone else is going to switch from VHS, so we all buy VHS. If we could all coordinate our behavior, we would all buy Beta.] 3. The lock-in stories have played a large role in the case against Microsoft, first with Gary Reback's tirades and then in the justice department briefs and the judge's decision. 4. This concern with locking-in consumers has led some Internet companies to foolishly go for market share at all costs. This bad strategy is in part responsible for the current meltdown in Internet stocks. In fact, our evidence shows that consumers will make a change to a better product if one comes along. Our evidence also shows no support for a 'tipping point' although it has often been theorized. Instead superior products gain market share at a fairly constant rate. 5. We have also argued that network effects are probably less important than more traditional economies of scale for most software products, and that in some cases network effects would be unimportant for software products. (network effects are indirect here, meaning that consumers do not get direct benefits just because someone is part of a network, but benefit in indirect ways, such as easier transferal of files). There is no good evidence measuring the importance of indirect network effects, which of course doesn't mean that they are not be important in some cases. The four or five studies trying to estimate these effects are all seriously flawed. 6. AOL's instant messaging has powerful direct network effects. It is in AOL's interest to keep its standards proprietary as long as consumers don't object. But if a better system comes along, or if consumers want more compatibility, AOL will have to change (just as all the online services found that they needed to provide Internet connectivity when the Internet became popular) if it wants to avoid being dislodged. If consumers are content with AOL's product as it stands, there is no problem, except for AOL's competitors. Antitrust law is not meant to help competitors, but to help consumers. I am not aware of any evidence indicating that the government should force AOL to open up its system. Obviously, I disagree with Microsoft on this issue and think they are being hypocritical. Now I have some responses to claims that I found in the discussion. The tone of some of these claims makes it difficult to respond in an evenhanded manner, but I am trying to keep the conversation at a somewhat adult level. Kevin Coates claims that this lock-in theory isn't central to the case, but he is mistaken. The application-barrier-to-entry is a network effect, and it is central to the judge's thinking. Mr. Coates says: "The authors look at network effects arguments, and try and analyze whether Microsoft's leading products lead as a result of their superior quality. They make some interesting points, but how is that crucial to the specific anti-trust allegations leveled against Microsoft?" The answer is that it is crucial to the government's case. The fact that Navigator fell to Internet Explorer is at the heart of the government's case. Our evidence shows that it can be explained by the quality difference, whereas the government claimed it was due to Microsoft's restricting Netscape's ability to get their product to market. Knowing which interpretation is correct allows one to decide much of the case. Wayne Jones states: "This reinforces why I brought up AOL as an example. AOL is a pretty good example of the early stages of de facto lock-in via network effects (Windows being an example of late-stage lock-in where a platform shift would be near impossible for many applications developers). Some on the forum seem to doubt the antitrust relevance of network effects, even if such a phenomenon exists. The relevance is this: once first-mover status has been secured and customers sign on to a given protocol, the number of customers using that protocol becomes a barrier to entry because new customers will be more inclined to use a protocol that gives them access to other customers than to go with a relatively un-established protocol (Beta being a really tired example of this. LPs, in an odd way, are another example, since consumers would not buy a record player to play new content...it simply isn't being released any more)." The problem with this is the use of the term lock-in. We are all locked-in to eating and breathing, but that is not a bad thing. Lock-in as it is used in this literature is bad because a majority of consumers are locked-in to using products that they really would rather not be using. New entrants will find that they have to have better products to dislodge an incumbent. But so what? In this hypothetical, it doesn't matter which product is used and if new entrants have problems it is of little matter to the economy. AOL instant messaging is, however, a good example of a market with strong network effects. Mr. Hallam-Baker requires more time since he has written so much and his dislike of David Theroux is apparently so strong that he apparently has no interest in a real discussion of the issues. He is correct that Qwerty and Betamax are not the leading examples of network effects, but they are by far the leading examples of lock-in. the QWERTY story, brought to economics by Paul David (although Brian Arthur claims David took it from him) is particularly famous. These lock-in examples are factually incorrect. For whatever reason, Mr. Hallem-Baker feels perfectly free to bluster away with misinformed statements: "Microsoft won because of superior reviews? Come on, how stupid do you think we are? So if a company pays for glowing reviews that would be okay?" If he had tried looking at what we had written before spouting off, he would have realized that in many cases we found the product with the better reviews to be the company that was not the bigger advertiser: Quicken when Managing Your Money was the leader; Quark, when Pagemaker was the leader; Excel, when Lotus was the larger firm; and so forth. If Mr. Hallem-Baker discards all information found in advertising supported magazines that is his business, but there is strong evidence that advertising doesn't buy the better review. I do agree with his views that just about any good argument should be understandable by the layman, but it might take a little effort on the reader's part. Our book is written for just such an audience, as he would have realized if he had bothered to look at it. But we at least have to understand what we mean by terms such as network effect and lock-in before there can be a useful discussion. His quoting from the Economist misses the point. Lock-in is inefficient when we as a group fail to choose the better product because the group cannot coordinate its behavior. It doesn't require irrational behavior on the part of any individual-in fact each individual is assumed rational. He states: "I read the L-M evidence and came to a quite different conclusion. They discounted all evidence pointing to the fact that a re-organized keyboard could be more efficient as 'biased' but do not point to [I think he means 'discount'] independent trials that found QWERTY better. The most obvious explanation for this is that the obvious costs of retraining the typists compared to the possible advantage meant that nobody thought it worth bothering to even *try* to break the QWERTY dominance." If he had read our paper he would know that many organizations were considering making just such a change and based their decision on a study run by the General Services Administration in the 1950s. That study concluded that there was no advantage in switching. The main evidence to the contrary was a Navy study that in fact was biased. It did not treat the Qwerty group the same as the Dvorak group and this bias increased the reported advantage of the Dvorak group. We don't even know if the control group was a fair control. And the study appears to have been conducted by the creator of the alternative keyboard, who was then a Lieutenant Commander in the Navy in charge of such things. Other studies that we tended to discount did not have any control group and we don't take them too seriously because it is well known that typing speed will increase for any format if you put typists in (re)training programs. Without a control group such examinations are meaningless. Seth Finkelstein reports on a debate in the Economic History (not our field) discussion group where we were asked to provide the starting article so that other could debate the concept of path dependence. He quotes Richard Rosenbloom as debunking our Beta/VHS story. Although Richard disagrees with our conclusion that alliances didn't matter, he doesn't disagree with our more important conclusion that Beta wasn't better than VHS. I still do not agree with his claim that alliances were the key. He was also probably annoyed that we didn't cite his article with Cusomano where they claim that VHS won largely because Sony didn't have as powerful a group of firms following its lead as did VHS. We should have cited their article, but the fact is that we based our analysis on a book that I believe to be at least equally well researched as their article. It is also the case that the size of the coalition is itself a function of which standard looks more likely to win on the merits. VHS's longer playing time was the only serious difference between the formats and was responsible for RCA going with VHS when it might otherwise have gone with Sony. Finkelstein also gives some links to recent works of Paul David whose Qwerty story we debunked in 1990. Although David is a well-known economic historian, there is nothing in his articles that questions our dismantling of his QWERTY story. Instead he questions our definitions of path dependence because he is concerned that it is becoming too popular in the economics profession. His anger is so great (the QWERTY piece is by far his most famous), and his arguments so distorted (his major claim is that we don't follow chaos theory closely enough), that it isn't surprising that he hasn't been able to publish these articles now going on five years. Go ahead and read them, but make sure you read ours too. Judge the work, not which university we are at. Finally Finkelstein (what is the source of his anger, anyway?) claims that we are merely Panglossians, believing that this is the best of all possible worlds. I wonder what is the source of his claim? He won't find it in our papers, which I doubt that he read. Probably it is something he took out of Paul David's screed. Why he would read our critics and not bother reading our papers I do not know. We do believe markets make mistakes. But the large types of mistakes that David talks about (turning down investments in keyboards that provide a return on investment of 2200%) doesn't seem to us very likely to happen. Brad de Long says that we believe the burden of proof lies with those who believe QWERTY worlds exist [actually he says we don't believe in network effects, but he knows better and presumably just carelessly typed]. He is correct. We do believe they need to come up with some examples. But our reasons are not hidden or inexplicable. QWERTY economics is a new theory. The old theory generally worked pretty well. QWERTY aficionados believe we should have the government act on the basis of these theories. All we are asking is a single piece of support for the theory. The other side says that it should be presumed that QWERTY instances happen and that Margolis and I need to prove they never do. I view this as analogous to cold fusion. Is it asking too much to request that the proponents provide at least one instance where it works? I think not. The alternative, that anti-cold fusion proponents prove that cold fusion never works is unreasonable. Asking us to prove that a QWERTY-type lock-in never has occurred is an impossible task although asking the other side to find but a single case should not be too difficult a task. The fact is, if they had even a single case, [QWERTY, or Beta, or whatever] they wouldn't be objecting to this fairly trivial burden of proof, would they? This demonstrates quite nicely that even Paul David doesn't believe they yet have a reasonable instance of a QWERTY world. And speaking about how the world looks DeLong states: "But while that is important from the perspective of intellectual originality, it seems beside the point as far as understanding the world is concerned..." If I understand him, Brad is interested in theories that talk about how the world actually works. This is exactly what I am interested in, which is why I believe that so much that passes as pure theory is useless. But surely, how can a theory that has no supporting empirical evidence be useful in telling us how the world runs? _________________ Stan Liebowitz Professor of Managerial Economics University of Texas at Dallas 972-883-2807, fax 972-883-2818 ********************************************************************** For Listserv Instructions, see http://www.lawlists.net/cyberia Off-Topic threads: http://www.lawlists.net/mailman/listinfo/cyberia-ot Need more help? Send mail to: Cyberia-L-Request@listserv.aol.com ********************************************************************** --- end forwarded text -- ----------------- R. A. Hettinga <mailto: rah@ibuc.com> The Internet Bearer Underwriting Corporation <http://www.ibuc.com/> 44 Farquhar Street, Boston, MA 02131 USA "... however it may deserve respect for its usefulness and antiquity, [predicting the end of the world] has not been found agreeable to experience." -- Edward Gibbon, 'Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire' _______________________________________________ Nettime-bold mailing list Nettime-bold@nettime.org http://www.nettime.org/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/nettime-bold